Maryland (State or other jurisdiction of incorporation or organization) |
1-11718 (Commission File No.) |
36-3857664 (IRS Employer Identification Number) |
Two North Riverside Plaza, Chicago, Illinois (Address of principal executive offices) |
60606 (Zip Code) |
Item 8.01 | Other Events |
Item 9.01 | Financial Statements and Exhibits |
Exhibit 99.1
|
January 29, 2008 Findings of Facts, Conclusions of Law and Order Thereon of the United States District Court for the Northern District of California regarding Equity LifeStyle Properties, Inc. and the City of San Rafael. |
EQUITY LIFESTYLE PROPERTIES, INC. |
||||
Date: January 31, 2008 | By: | /s/ Michael B. Berman | ||
Michael B. Berman | ||||
Executive Vice President and Chief Financial Officer |
||||
MHC FINANCING, LTD, et al, | No C-00-03785 VRW | |||||
Plaintiffs, | FINDINGS OF FACTS, | |||||
CONCLUSIONS OF LAW | ||||||
v | AND ORDER THEREON | |||||
CITY OF SAN RAFAEL, | ||||||
Defendant, | ||||||
CONTEMPO MARIN HOMEOWNERS | ||||||
ASSOCIATION, |
||||||
Defendant-Intervenor. | ||||||
/
|
2
1. | Plaintiffs are MHC Financing Limited Partnership (now known as Equity LifeStyle Properties, Inc) and Grapeland Vistas, Inc. For ease of exposition, the court refers to plaintiffs collectively as MHC unless otherwise noted. MHC operates as a real estate investment trust, or REIT, and is publicly traded on the New York Stock Exchange. 10/30/02 Tr at 69:1-2. The REIT provides a structure for investors to pool their resources in real estate or rental properties similar to that which mutual funds provide for investment in stocks and bonds. 10/30/02 Tr at 69:3-7. |
3
2. | Defendant is the City of San Rafael (City or San Rafael). Located approximately 15 miles north of San Francisco, San Rafael is the county seat of Marin County, California. 10/30/02 Tr at 74:9-11. | |
3. | Contempo Marin Homeowners Association (CMHA), an unincorporated association, is a defendant-intervenor in this action. CMHA seeks to uphold the legality of the Ordinance. | |
4. | A mobilehome or manufactured home is a dwelling constructed at a factory and then moved and installed at another site. 11/25/02 Tr at 38:22-39:6. | |
5. | Contempo Marin Mobilehome Park (Contempo Marin) is a mobilehome park located in San Rafael. There are 396 mobilehome spaces at Contempo Marin, and approximately 1000 people live at the park. 4/24/07 Tr at 467:25-468:10. | |
6. | Contempo Marin is one of two facilities to which San Rafael applies the Ordinance. The other facility is known as RV Park of San Rafael, a 30-site park populated with campers, RVs [and] trailers rather than mobilehomes. 11/5/02 at 67:16-24; 4/11/07 Tr at 391:18-392:17. The units at the RV Park have wheels, are attached to wheeled vehicles or are capable of having wheels mounted. The RV Park has limited amenities. Due to the mobility of most of its units and its limited amenities, the RV Park is not comparable to Contempo Marin. Consequently, Contempo Marin is the sole location of its type in San Rafael and thus offers a unique form of housing in San Rafael. | |
7. | At Contempo Marin, MHC leases plots of land, called pads or spaces for the purpose of installing a mobilehome on the |
4
8. | Pad lessees at Contempo Marin who wish to relocate have usually sold their mobilehomes in place rather than pulling them from the park and moving them to another location. In the case of in-place transfers of mobilehomes at Contempo Marin, purchasers, in addition to acquiring the mobilehome, take over the pad leasehold on which the mobilehome is located and the right of access to and use of the various community facilities. California law entitles in-place transferees to assume the prior lessees lease with its attendant rights. | |
9. | Pad lessees at Contempo Marin are subject to rules created by MHC and its predecessor. Those rules allow only new mobilehomes to be placed on vacant pads. In addition, these rules require the removal of the mobilehomes axel once situated on a pad and provide that the cost of installing utility connections, a garage, steps, porches, decks and landscaping must be borne by the pad lessee. The cost of maintaining these improvements, as well as fencing, driveways and walkways, is also borne by the pad lessee. | |
10. | Pad lessees at Contempo Marin own and maintain their individual mobilehomes. Pad lessees pay monthly rent to MHC for use of their respective pads and the community facilities and services that MHC provides. MHC holds legal title to the |
5
11. | As of 2002, the average tenure of Contempo Marin residents is about ten years. 10/30/02 Tr at 83:6-10; City Trial Ex EX. | |
12. | Housing costs in the San Francisco Bay area are among the highest in the United States. Mobilehomes at Contempo Marin offer certain cost advantages over traditional or stick built housing: (a) mobilehomes at Contempo Marin are largely assembled in a factory employing mass production techniques; and (b) a mobilehome pad lessee at Contempo Marin avoids the capital outlay required to own the ground upon which the mobilehome sits. Offsetting these advantages, however, interest rates for the purchase of a mobilehome are generally higher than for stick built housing due to the lower residual |
6
value and shorter useful life of mobilehomes. MHC Trial Ex 105 at 15-17; 11/19/02 Tr at 76. | ||
13. | In 1977, the Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD) established certain guidelines for mobilehomes. As a general rule, mobilehomes produced before implementation of these guidelines command less value than mobilehomes produced in accordance with these guidelines. Availability of financing for the purchase of pre-HUD guideline mobilehomes is essentially non-existent from conventional lenders in the San Francisco Bay area. 10/30/02 Tr at 77:15-17, 79:6-21. |
14. | Post-HUD guideline mobilehomes are more comparable to stick built homes than pre-HUD guideline homes. Post-HUD mobilehomes average more than 1400 square feet and have features such as peaked roofs, porches, bay windows, fireplaces, designer kitchens and fully appointed baths. Post-HUD guideline mobilehomes sell on average for approximately $60,000. City Trial Ex BV; 11/21/02 Tr at 88:12-89:15. |
15. | Formerly, most of the mobilehomes at Contempo Marin were manufactured before 1976 and thus were not subject to the HUD guidelines. In order to upgrade the park, MHC has purchased some of these older mobilehomes, obtained their offsite salvage values and replaced them with newer, post-HUD mobilehomes. This effort increased the desirability of Contempo Marin as a residential location and benefitted the remaining Contempo Marin pad lessees. |
16. | Contempo Marin contains less than 2 percent of the housing units in San Rafael and less than 4/10ths of 1 percent of the |
7
17. | In 1978, California enacted the California Mobilehome Residency Law, Cal Civ Code §§ 798 et seq. The legislature found that because of the high cost of moving mobilehomes, the potential for damage resulting therefrom, the requirements relating to the installation of mobilehomes, and the cost of landscaping or lot preparation, it is necessary that the owners of mobilehomes occupied within mobilehome parks [i e, pad lessees] be provided with the unique protection from actual or constructive eviction afforded by the provisions of this chapter. Cal Civ Code § 798.55(a). |
18. | The California Mobilehome Residency Law provides pad lessees an ongoing tenancy that can be terminated only at the option of the pad lessee. A park owner may terminate a leasehold only for cause, as defined by the statute, such as the nonpayment of rent or the failure to abide by park rules. Id § 798.56. The law also permits pad lessees to sell their coaches in-place to purchasers who must be offered a tenancy for the pad. Id §§ 798.17, 798.18, 798.73, 798.75. This |
8
restriction on mobilehome park owners stands in contrast to Californias property tax regime, under which municipalities that provide comparable services, such as roads, parks, walking trails, libraries and other recreational amenities, obtain a stepped-up tax upon the resale of property. See section 2 of article XIIIA of the California Constitution (enacted by Proposition 13) (establishing an acquisition-value assessment system). | ||
19. | The California Mobilehome Residency Law permits mobilehome
landowners to negotiate rental agreements of longer than
twelve months duration that are exempt from rent control. See
Cal Civ Code § 798.17. But the statute grants tenants a right
to refuse a long-term lease and be offered a rent controlled
lease with the same rental charges, terms, and conditions
* * * during the first 12 months. Id § 798.17(c). |
20. | In 1989, the City enacted the Mobilehome Rent Stabilization Ordinance, San Rafael Municipal Code Chapter 20.04 (the 1989 Ordinance). The 1989 Ordinance limited annual rent increases that mobilehome park owners could charge pad lessees to a graduated percentage of the California, All Urban Consumers, San Francisco-Oakland-San Jose index (CPI-C). Id, § 20.04.040(B). If the change in CPI-C was 5 percent or less, the park owner was entitled to increase pad rents by a percentage equal to the change in CPI-C. Id. If the CPI-C increased between 5 percent and 10 percent, the park owner could raise pad rents by a percentage equal to 75 percent of the overall change in CPI-C. Id. If the CPI-C increase was greater than 10 percent, the park owner could increase pad |
9
rents by a percentage equal to 66 percent of the overall change in CPI-C. Id. Under the 1989 Ordinance, park owners could seek a greater increase through a defined process. Id, § 20.10.180. | ||
21. | The purpose of the 1989 Ordinance was to establish a speedy and efficient method of reviewing rent increases in mobilehome parks to protect homeowners [ie, pad lessees] from arbitrary, capricious or unreasonable rent increases while insuring owners and/or operators and investors a fair and reasonable return and encouraging competition in the provision of mobilehome lots. Id, § 20.04.010(J). The 1989 Ordinance contained a finding that mobilehomes constitute an important source of housing for persons of low and moderate income. Id, § 20.04.010(B). The 1989 Ordinance described many pad lessees as elderly, some of whom live on small fixed incomes and who may expend a substantial portion of their income on rent and may not be able to afford other housing within the city. Id, § 20.04.010. |
22. | The 1989 Ordinance did not contain vacancy control provisions. The park owner was thus able to raise the pad rent, irrespective of rent control, charged to a new pad lessee who took over the prior pad lessees lease. See MHC Ex 104 (Quigley report) at 5 (explaining that under vacancy control, the right to rent the pad at the regulated price is transferred to a new lessee at the then current pad rental value). |
23. | In 1993, the City amended the 1989 Ordinance to include vacancy control provisions (1993 Amendments). In so doing, |
10
a. | Establishment of rent regulations on spaces where ownership of the mobilehome is transferred but the mobilehome remains, sometimes referred to as vacancy control, is an important part of rent control policy as it protects mobilehome owners from excessive space rent increases and permits sales of mobilehomes without unconscionable rent increases to the new owner; |
b. | Rent control regulations, including vacancy control, can assist in providing affordable housing in combination with city programs and actions to help provide a variety of housing types within a range of costs affordable to low and very low income households; |
c. | A significant number of residents have become residents following the effective date of [the 1989 Ordinance] and were required to pay a rental rate substantially higher than comparable spaces; and |
d. | Many residents of such spaces are senior citizens on fixed incomes and have been forced to pay unnecessarily high rents and/or have been constrained in their ability to sell their mobilehomes. |
24. | Prior to enactment of the 1993 Amendments, when a tenant terminated tenancy at Contempo Marin and either sold his mobilehome to an incoming tenant or removed the mobilehome, MHC was able to negotiate a new rent with an incoming tenant. This allowed MHC to realize the fair market rental of the mobilehome pad. |
25. | Prior to enactment of the 1993 Amendments, the City did not |
11
conduct an investigation or other inquiry to determine any of the facts stated as grounds for enactment of the 1993 Amendments. The City did not have a factual basis to make any finding that MHC charged or attempted to charge excessive or unconscionable space rent increases upon in-place transfers of mobilehomes at Contempo Marin, Contempo Marin residents were required to pay a rental rate substantially higher than comparable spaces or Contempo Marin residents have been forced to pay unnecessarily high rents and/or have been constrained in their ability to sell their mobilehomes. There was in fact no basis for any of the stated grounds for the enactment of the 1993 Amendments. | ||
26. | At the time the 1993 Amendments were enacted, Contempo Marin was owned by De Anza Assets, Inc (De Anza). |
27. | On April 19, 1993, De Anza filed suit in Marin County superior court, De Anza Assets, Inc v City of San Rafael, Case No AO63017. |
28. | There, De Anza alleged that the 1993 Amendments amounted to a regulatory taking in violation of the Takings Clause of the Fifth Amendment to the United States Constitution. |
29. | The superior court sustained a demurrer to the De Anza first amended complaint without leave to amend on the basis that De Anza had not stated and could not state a cause of action. |
30. | While an appeal of the superior courts demurrer was pending, in August 1994, MHC purchased Contempo Marin and has continued to operate the park to the present. |
31. | On October 6, 1994, the state court of appeal affirmed in part and reversed in part the superior courts grant of a demurrer |
12
and remanded the case to the superior court. While the court of appeal concluded that the Amendments do not constitute a regulatory taking, it nonetheless reversed and remanded on other grounds. City Trial Ex BR at 15. | ||
32. | The parties in the De Anza litigation took no further action. On November 5, 2002, the superior court dismissed the De Anza litigation for failure to prosecute. | |
33. | MHC is not affiliated with the plaintiffs in the De Anza litigation. |
34. | On November 1, 1999, the City further amended its mobilehome rent control ordinance by enacting the regulation here at issue (the 1999 Amendments).* The City replaced the sliding scale formula of the 1993 Amendments that provided for graduated annual rent increases depending on the magnitude of inflation, with a single formula that limited increases to 75 percent of any increase in the CPI-C. City Trial Ex AI. In addition, the 1999 Amendments modified the manner in which the cost of capital improvements could be recovered by park owners. Id. |
35. | San Rafaels mobilehome rent regulation provides an administrative procedure by which park
owners such as MHC may seek rent increases beyond that which the regulations formula provides
in order to obtain a just and reasonable return. City Trial Ex AB § 20.12.050. |
* | The Ordinance as amended in 1999 is set out in the Appendix showing the deletions and additions made by the 1999 Amendments. |
13
36. | On October 13, 2000, MHC commenced the instant suit challenging the constitutionality of the Citys regulations on the ground that they violate the Takings Clause of the Fifth Amendment as made applicable to the states by the Fourteenth Amendment. See Doc #1. |
37. | Coupled with the earlier enactments, the 1999 Amendments changed the operation of San Rafaels mobilehome rent regulation to render it certain that mobilehome pad rents would fall progressively further behind market rents. |
38. | Prior to the 1999 Amendments, the automatic rent increase formula provided that rent increases could essentially keep pace with the prevailing rates of inflation. Under the prior regime, park owners were automatically entitled to increase rents by 100 percent of the change in the CPI-C if the annual increase was 5 percent or less in a given year. In no year from 1993 to 1999 did the CPI-C increase at an annual rate greater than 5 percent. See Bureau of Labor Statistics, United States Dept of Labor website, at http://data.bls.gov/PDQ/servlet/SurveyOutputServlet?data_tool=dropmap&series_id=CUURA422SA0,CUUSA422SA0 (change output options) (last visited January 26, 2008). |
39. | The 1999 Amendments, coupled with the vacancy control provision of the 1993 Amendments, impose a continually growing gap between the fair market rental value of a mobilehome pad leasehold and the rental rate MHC is permitted to charge at Contempo Marin. During its first year of operation, the |
14
40. | After ten years, the increase in the fair market value of the leasehold would be approximately 30 percent greater than the increase in the amount paid by pad lessees under the 1999 Amendments. Because the formula prior to the 1999 Amendments provided for rent increases to rise at 100 percent of inflation if the local CPI-C increased by 5 percent or less, the increase in the amount paid by pad lessees under the previous formula would also be 30 percent greater than the cumulative increase allowed under the 1999 Amendments. After thirty years, the gap between the rent under the pre-1999 formula and the rent permitted under the 1999 Amendments rises to 40 percent. See also 11/6/02 Tr at 197:5-198:3. |
41. | The 1999 Amendments created a premium in the resale prices of |
15
mobilehomes located in Contempo Marin. This premium corresponds to and is equal to the capitalized value of the difference between the fair market rental value of mobilehome pads at Contempo Marin and the rental permitted to be charged under the 1999 Amendments. MHC Trial Ex 104 (Quigley report) at 6-8; MHC Trial Ex 137 at 3. | ||
42. | Under operation of the 1999 Amendments, the economic value of the below fair market rent for
the mobilehome pad is simply capitalized into the selling price of the mobile home in the
event of an in-place transfer. Indeed, the amendments reduced MHCs revenue streams from
Contempo Marin and the value of its property by $10,609,136. See MHC Trial Ex 103 (Fischel
report) at 30; 11/6/02 Tr at 196:5-197:3. |
43. | In making in-place transfers of mobilehomes at Contempo Marin, purchasers and sellers negotiate one sales price. This sales price is composed of the replacement value of the mobilehome itself and the premium attributable to San Rafaels regulation of mobilehome pad rentals. Parties do not separately negotiate these two components of value. Estimates must be made to determine these components of value. The most reliable and widely used source of estimates of the replacement value of mobilehomes at Contempo Marin are found in the data compiled by the National Automobile Dealers Association (NADA). Estimates of replacement value in the NADA guides make adjustments for transportation and setup costs and tenant improvements such as carports, porches, awnings, additions and the like. Insurance rates for mobilehomes at Contempo Marin are based on replacement values. |
16
44. | The average replacement value of the mobilehomes sold at Contempo Marin between January 1999 and July 2002 was approximately $27,000. Most of these sales (fifty-nine out of sixty-nine) occurred after enactment of the 1999 Amendments. |
45. | Since the 1999 Amendments, including the several years that elapsed from the commencement of this action to the start of trial, San Rafaels scheme of mobilehome rent regulation created a premium in the price of mobilehomes sold in place at Contempo Marin. Purchasers of mobilehomes in Contempo Marin after the 1999 Amendments have paid a premium reflecting the present value of expected rent savings due to San Rafael rent regulation. This premium averages $67,000 for the right to enjoy the below market regulated rent. |
46. | The premium paid by new pad lessees in Contempo Marin who purchased existing mobilehomes following enactment of the 1999 Amendments reflected nearly full monetization of the expected rent benefits of the 1999 Amendments. See MHC Ex 137 (Quigley supp) at 3 (estimating the premium plus associated financing costs to represent nearly 100 percent of the economic benefits under the 1999 Amendments). Commencing in 2000, MHC provided a notice to all incoming pad lessees of the pendency of this lawsuit and the possibility that rent control and/or vacancy control for mobilehome pad rentals in San Rafael may be eliminated. On July 13, 2001, San Rafael through its city attorneys office notified Contempo Marin residents that it had entered into a settlement agreement with MHC to eliminate the Citys mobilehome vacancy control regulations. The difference between full capitalization of expected rent |
17
control benefits to existing pad lessees of the 1999 Amendments is the product of incoming tenants uncertainty concerning the continued viability of rent and vacancy control at Contempo Marin. If the 1999 Amendments are determined to be constitutional, full capitalization (100 percent) of the below-market rentals produced by the 1999 Amendments will be realized by existing pad lessees at Contempo Marin. See 11/27/02 Tr at 70:12-19. | ||
47. | The evidence presented in 2007 corroborates the courts capitalization analysis. In 2007, MHCs expert, Dr Quigley, used a data source for real estate sale prices different from the NADA valuation he relied on in 2002. Quigleys findings and regression analysis nonetheless yield consistent results, namely, that the benefits that arise from the Ordinance were capitalized into higher selling prices of mobilehome coaches in Contempo Marin. 4/24/2007 Tr at 482:14-483:21; 502:11-19; MHC Trial Ex 392. |
48. | The level of capitalization would be even greater but for the uncertainty about the future of the rent regulation due to this litigation. 4/24/2007 Tr at 502:11-503:9, 502:22-503:9. |
49. | Since the 2002 trial, the average sales price for mobilehomes sold have risen to $119,606, City Trial Ex EV; Ex 392, yielding an average premium in excess of $98,000 and representing about 82 percent of the value of the transaction. 4/24/07 Tr at 612:25-613:3; MHC Trial Ex 392 at 9913. In 2007, 21 mobilehomes sold in Contempo Marin at a mean price of $154,000, MHC Trial Ex 400. Most of these units were pre-HUD mobilehomes. 4/30/07 Tr at 782:13-20; 783:11-21. |
18
50. | According to the annual letters sent by MHC to the City for the purpose of calculating the annual automatic rent pursuant to the Ordinance, the average monthly space rents at Contempo Marin for 1999 through 2006 were as follows: |
1999: |
$ | 613.73 | ||
2000: |
$ | 630.43 | ||
2001: |
$ | 654.24 | ||
2002: |
$ | 663.65 | ||
2003: |
$ | 652.81 | ||
2004: |
$ | 659.31 | ||
2005: |
$ | 664.85 | ||
2006: |
$ | 675.32 |
51. | As a result of the capitalization of below market mobilehome pad rentals into the resale price of mobilehomes at Contempo Marin, the Citys mobilehome rent control regulations do not contribute to the availability of low-cost (i e, below market rate) housing in San Rafael. Nor do the regulations foster the availability of housing to senior citizens as the value of the below market pad rentals available at Contempo Marin is greater, other factors being the same, to a prospective purchaser having a longer rather than shorter life expectancy. |
52. | For new or prospective mobilehome residents at Contempo Marin, their cost of housing includes both cash outlays or finance payments for the mobilehome as well as the pad rental. The total economic cost of housing at Contempo Marin remains at market levels because of the increased cost of the mobilehome necessary to impound the capitalized value of below market pad rentals. The 1999 Amendments transfer the capitalized value of the difference between market pad rentals at Contempo Marin |
19
from plaintiffs to pad lessees in possession of Contempo Marin pads at the time of the effectiveness of the 1999 Amendments. | ||
53. | The City presented evidence purporting to show that the difference between the selling prices of mobilehomes after enactment of the 1999 Amendments and the book values for those homes, as published in the NADA Mobile/Manufacture Housing Appraisal Guide, were not the result of the Ordinance. The City introduced a study of mobilehome parks located in other cities that are not subject to rent control. See City Ex 106 (Brabant report) at 21-25. The study concluded that the recent sale prices of mobilehomes in those parks were comparable to recent sale prices in Contempo Marin, as measured on a per-square-foot basis. Id at 25. This evidence is not credible due to the failure of this presentation to control for variation in the quality of the mobilehome parks used for comparison. |
54. | The Citys expert also opined that the higher sales prices of mobilehomes in Contempo Marin, compared to their NADA book values, were attributable not to the capitalization of the benefits of below-market rent but rather the desirability of Contempo Marins location. See Brabant Report (City Ex 106), at 20. The locational value of a mobilehome in Contempo Marin is not the product of any investment of a Contempo Marin mobilehome owner, by situating a mobilehome on a pad at Contempo Marin and connecting utilities to the mobilehome or otherwise. 11/25/02 Tr at 141:4-142:6. |
55. | The premium by which Contempo Marin-located mobilehomes exceed their NADA book values is six to eight times larger than the |
20
location value claimed by the City. Id at 132:10-133:2. The Citys argument pertaining to location value simply does not account for the magnitude of the premium observed; nor does it undermine the evidence that the economic benefits of the Ordinance will be monetized and transferred to mobilehome owners who had leases in Contempo Marin at the time of its amendment. | ||
56. | Finally, the City also objects to MHCs expert report on the ground that its reliance on NADA book values is erroneous. While the City contends that MHCs experts lacked the necessary background and training to apply the information contained in the NADA book, the City fails to point to any logical or foundational deficiencies in those experts testimony. |
57. | The Takings Clause of the Fifth Amendment of the United States Constitution states, in relevant part, [N]or shall private property be taken for public use, without just compensation. US Const amend V. The Takings Clause applies to the states through the Fourteenth Amendment. See, e g, Dolan v City of Tigard, 512 US 374, 383-84 (1984). |
58. | [W]hile property may be regulated to a certain extent, if regulation goes too far it will be recognized as a taking. Pennsylvania Coal Co v Mahon, 260 US 393, 415 (1922). |
59. | The Takings Clauses proper role is to [bar] government from forcing some people alone to bear public burdens which, in all fairness and justice, should be borne by the public as a |
21
whole. Lingle v Chevron USA, Inc, 544 US 528, 537 (2005), quoting Armstrong v United States, 364 US 40, 49 (1960) (internal quotations omitted). Nevertheless, states retain broad power to regulate * * * the landlord-tenant relationship * * * without paying compensation for all economic injuries that such regulation entails. Loretto v Teleprompter Manhattan CATV Corp, 458 US 419, 440 (1982). | ||
60. | [W]here the government merely regulates the use of property, compensation is required only if considerations such as the purpose of the regulation or the extent to which it deprives the owner of the economic use of the property suggest that the regulation has unfairly singled out the property owner to bear a burden that should be borne by the public as a whole. Yee v City of Escondido, 503 US 519, 522-23 (1992). |
61. | The Penn Central factors though each has given rise to vexing subsidiary questions have served as the principal guidelines for resolving regulatory takings claims * * *. Lingle, 544 US at 538-39. |
62. | Regulatory takings jurisprudence aims to identify regulatory actions that are functionally equivalent to the classic taking in which the government directly appropriates private property or ousts the owner from his domain. * * * [T]he Penn Central inquiry turns in large part, albeit not exclusively, upon the magnitude of a regulations economic impact and the degree to which it interferes with legitimate property interests. Lingle, 544 US at 539-40, quoting Penn Central Transp Co v City of New York, 438 US 104, 124 (1978) (internal quotations omitted). |
22
63. | In addition, the character of the governmental action for instance whether it amounts to a physical invasion or instead merely affects property interests through some public program adjusting the benefits and burdens of economic life to promote the common good may be relevant in discerning whether a taking has occurred. Id, quoting Penn Central, 438 US at 124 (internal quotations omitted). The court addresses each Penn Central factor in turn. |
64. | The Supreme Court has measured economic impact in several different ways, including assessing the market value of the property, see Hodel v Irving, 481 US 704, 714 (1987), determining whether the regulation makes the property owners business operation commercially impracticable, Keystone, 480 US at 493-96 (1987), and evaluating the possibility of other economic uses of the land besides sale, see Andrus v Allard, 444 US 51, 66 (1979). |
65. | The court should consider, along with other relevant matters, the relationship of the owners basis or investment, and the fair market value before the alleged taking to the fair market value after the alleged taking. In determining the severity of the economic impact, the owners opportunity to recoup its investment or better, subject to the regulation, cannot be ignored. Florida Rock Indus v United States, 18 F3d 1560, 1566-67 (Fed Cir 1994) (Florida Rock IV), quoting Florida Rock Indus v United States, 791 F2d 893, 905 (Fed Cir 1986) (Florida Rock II). |
23
66. | Since loss of economic use and value is the issue in this regulatory taking case, it is not possible, absent a valid determination in the record of the after imposition value of the land, to know if a taking occurred, much less what the Government must pay for it. Florida Rock IV, 18 F3d at 1573. |
67. | The Ninth Circuit defined economic impact in the context of a regulatory takings claim in Garneau v City of Seattle, holding that plaintiffs must show that the value of their property diminished as a consequence of the [ordinance at issue]. Further, plaintiffs must show that the diminution in value is so severe that the [ordinance at issue] has essentially appropriated their property for public use. 147 F3d 802, 808 (9th Cir 1998). |
68. | As explained, absent the Ordinance, MHC could obtain average rents in 2006 of approximately $1700 (and $1800 in 2007). 4/11/07 Tr at 418:13-18; 409:14-411:4. This estimation reflects a compound annual increase in rents of approximately 6 percent from 2001 to 2006. 5/1/07 Tr at 972:4-13. Lending support to these figures, the compounded annual increase from 1998 to 2006 for neighboring Captains Cove property is approximately 13 percent per year. 4/30/07 Tr at 972:14-973:23. |
69. | Rents under the Ordinance, however, were limited to under $700, City Trial Ex EX, depriving MHC of approximately $5.2 million in annual net operating income (NOI) ($1100 x 396 sites x 12 months). The Ordinance thus has the effect of eliminating at least 75 percent of the NOI that MHC would realize under market conditions. 5/1/07 Tr at 981:18-983:15; |
24
4/30/07 Tr at 834:25-835:11 (Citys expert, Dr Ken Baar, acknowledging that MHC is worth less than 25 percent of the value that it would have if MHC could collect market rents of $1800 a site). Consider Florida Rock Indus v United States, 45 Fed Cl 21, 33-38 (Fed Cl 1999) (Florida Rock V) (finding that the economic impact was severe because the property value diminished by 75 percent without offsetting benefits). | ||
70. | Compounding these losses, MHC remains responsible for maintaining and repairing an aging infrastructure and for incurring other capital expenditures without a reasonable means to recoup the capital, recover its costs of financing the same or obtaining a return on the same. 5/1/07 Tr 983:3-15; 4/11/07 Tr at 292:19-21. This state of affairs has led MHC to spend millions of dollars in legal fees simply to protect its property rights. 5/1/07 Tr at 979:20-980:20. |
71. | Based on the Citys own expert analysis, MHCs net operating income has declined over the last seven years even if legal expenses related to capital expenditures are not included as expenses. City Ex EO. Even if both legal expenses and expenses incurred by MHCs corporate office related to the park are excluded, its NOI has been completely frozen. Id. 4/30/07 Tr at 821:8-822:3. |
72. | Without the Ordinance, the park would be worth approximately $120 million. 5/1/07 Tr at 971:11-19. This valuation comports with the estimation of MHCs expert of the per parcel land value of $360,000, which amounts to a value of $140 million for the park. Further corroboration is found in the value of market rents for the park ($1800 a month in 2007), |
25
under which the NOI in 2007 would exceed $7 million. 4/11/07 Tr at 418:13-18; 409:14-411:4. Such an NOI level translates into a $118 million value for the park under a 6 percent capitalization rate, the rate suggested by the Citys expert. See 4/30/07 Tr at 743:9-13. | ||
73. | The Ordinance, however, deprives MHC of most of the parks value. The Citys expert valued the park at less than $23 million in 1999, MHC Trial Ex 13, and MHCs Chief Executive Officer asserts that the park is worth even less today. 5/1/07 Tr at 982:10-983:15. | |
74. | The Citys regulatory regime also prevents MHC from seeking investment alternatives for the park. The City intends to retain Contempo Marin as a mobilehome community. MHC Trial Ex 300; 4/9/07 Tr at 167:13-24 and 169:17-24. In accordance with its general plan, the City adopted a special zoning ordinance (no 1626), which designates Contempo Marin as a mobilehome park and proscribes any other use of the land. MHC Trial Ex 301. | |
75. | Because the City is obligated to follow its general plan, 4/11/07 Tr at 421:6-8, if MHC seeks to change the use of the park, it must convince the City to modify or repeal ordinance 1626. MHC Trial Ex 301; 4/11/07 Tr at 435:22-436:6 and 295:8- 24. Any change in zoning would require approval from the City council the same council that adopted ordinance 1626 and has committed in its general plan to retain Contempo Marin as a mobilehome park. 4/11/07 Tr at 436:7-24. | |
76. | To change the use of the park, MHC would need to obtain various permits, many of which would require approval by the |
26
City council. 4/11/07 Tr at 296:3-297:7 and 437:15-20. Even if MHC sought to subdivide the land, rather than change the use of each space, it would be required to obtain permits that require the City councils approval. 4/11/07 Tr at 296:3-12. | ||
77. | The Citys aims with respect to Contempo Marin are further evidenced by its reversal concerning the settlement the parties agreed to in July 2001, see Doc #23, Ex 1, § 2, under which the City agreed to initiate amendments to the ordinance that would eliminate vacancy control. The City reversed course in order to save the premiums obtained by Contempo Marin residents through operation of the Ordinance. This establishes that the City will not accept a change of use that displaced those residents. 4/11/07 Tr at 297:8-298:4. | |
78. | Owing to the political and litigation risks MHC would face in seeking a change of use and the costs, as demonstrated by MHCs efforts to obtain a discretionary rent increase, it would be commercially impracticable and wholly futile for MHC to seek a change of use. 4/11/07 Tr at 297:8-14. | |
79. | Nor does the prospect of selling the park alleviate the burden imposed on MHC. 5/1/07 Tr at 982:10-16. Inasmuch as the Citys conduct undermines MHCs investment it likewise diminishes the value of the park to prospective investors. MHCs ability to attract capital is similarly frustrated by the Citys regulations. 5/1/07 Tr at 983:3-984:1. | |
80. | Accordingly, the court concludes that the Ordinance imposed by the City is functionally equivalent to a physical taking of all or an overwhelming percentage of the value of MHCs land. |
27
81. | Evaluation of the degree of interference with investment- backed expectations instead is one factor that points toward the answer to the question whether the application of a particular regulation to particular property goes too far. Palazzolo v Rhode Island, 533 US 606, 634 (2001) (OConnor concurring) (emphasis in original). | |
82. | The Penn Central opinion suggested it is important whether or not the expected use of the property was the primary expectation for the property. Florida Rock Indus v United States. 45 Fed Cl 21, 38 (Fed Cl 1999) (Florida Rock V), citing Penn Central, 438 US at 136 (So the law does not interfere with what must be regarded as Penn Centrals primary expectation concerning the use of the parcel.) | |
83. | Although there is no right to recoup ones investment, the inability to do so weighs in plaintiffs favor, since the regulation consequently places a greater burden on plaintiff. Florida Rock V, 45 Fed Cl at 39. | |
84. | Marketplace decisions should be made under the working assumption that the Government will neither prejudice private citizens, unfairly shifting the burden of a public good onto a few people, nor act arbitrarily or capriciously, that is, will not act to disappoint reasonable investment-backed expectations. The Government, in a word, must act fairly and reasonably, so that private parties can pursue their interests. Florida Rock Indus v United States. 18 F3d 1560, 1571 (Fed Cir 1994) (Florida Rock IV). |
28
85. | A Penn Central claim is not barred by the mere fact that title was acquired after the effective date of the state- imposed restriction. Palazzolo, 533 US at 630. Nonetheless, the timing of the regulations enactment relative to the acquisition of title is not immaterial to the Penn Central analysis. Indeed, it would be just as much error to expunge this consideration from the takings inquiry as it would be to accord it exclusive significance. Palazzolo. 533 US at 633 (OConnor concurring). | |
86. | Before purchasing the park, MHCs business objectives were to acquire manufactured housing community properties that have strong cash flow growth potential and hold such properties for long-term investment and capital appreciation. 4/9/07 Tr at 20:15-24. | |
87. | Pursuant to this business plan, MHC purchased the Contempo Marin park as part of a portfolio transaction in which the company acquired approximately eleven properties (DeAnza Portfolio), 4/11/07 Tr at 309:14-310:4, which included rent controlled and non-rent controlled properties. MHCs expectations in purchasing the park were to achieve market appreciation over time. 4/9/07 Tr at 23:6-12. | |
88. | When MHC purchased the park in 1994, it had a reasonable expectation that it would be provided a reasonable return on its property value. | |
89. | The Citys amendments to the Ordinance in 1999 frustrated MHCs expectations by increasing dramatically the burden of the Ordinance on MHC. 4/11/07 Tr at 329:14-20; 5/1/07 Tr at 974:8-975:10 and 981:18-982:3. As set forth below, much of |
29
the economic injury suffered by MHC has been incurred after the enactment of the 1999 Ordinance, which MHC could not reasonably anticipate in 1994. According to the calculations of MHCs expert, the amendments immediately transferred $10 million from MHC to park tenants. Id; MHC Trial Ex 103. 5/1/07 Tr at 976:8-977:8. | ||
90. | Absent the Ordinance, MHC could obtain average rents in 2006 of approximately $1700 (and $1800 in 2007), as opposed to the $700 it presently receives. 4/11/07 Tr at 418:13-18; 409:14- 411:4. Starting from MHCs base rent from 1998, if MHC had been permitted to increase rent at a rate consistent with the rate of increase in housing costs in the immediate area, then MHC would have been able to increase its rents by approximately $900 a month during that period. Hence, approximately 90 percent ($900 out of $1000) of the economic impact of the Ordinance on MHCs rents is a function of the application of the Ordinance after 1999. | |
91. | Not only did the 1999 Amendments reduce the rent increases, but they changed the fair return standard in a way that impedes MHCs ability to obtain a return on capital expenditures. | |
92. | MHC had no reason to expect that the City would amend the Ordinance, transferring much of the parks value to third parties, 4/11/07 Tr at 329:19-20; 330:1-7, and denying MHC return on its capital in an escalating real estate market. 4/11/07 Tr at 292:19-21. |
30
93. | Accordingly, the Citys enforcement of the Ordinance has interfered with MHCs reasonable and investor-backed expectations. |
94. | The character of the government action being complained of is central to determining whether a regulatory taking has in fact occurred under Penn Central, To make this determination, courts look to balance the liberty interest of the private property owner against the Governments need to protect the public interest through imposition of the restraint. Cienega Gardens v United States, 331 F3d 1319, 1338 (Fed Cir 2003). | |
95. | Courts must also assess whether the relevant regulation forc[es] some people alone to bear public burdens which, in all fairness and justice, should be borne by the public as a whole. Armstrong v United States, 364 US 40, 49 (1960); see also Florida Rock Indus Inc v United States, 45 Fed Cl 21, 22 (Ct Cl 1999) (Florida Rock V) (stating that compensation is due under the Fifth Amendment where consideration of the Penn Central factors indicates that a plaintiff was singled out to bear a burden which ought to be paid for by the society as a whole); Nollan v California Coastal Commission, 483 US 825, 836 n4 (If the Nollans were being singled out to bear the burden of Californias attempt to remedy these problems, although they had not contributed to it more than other coastal landowners, the states action, even if otherwise valid, might violate * * * the Takings Clause.). |
31
96. | Through the Ordinance, the City has singled out MHC to bear a public burden that, in all fairness and justice, should be borne by the public as a whole. Contempo Marin and the RV Park are the only landowners in all of San Rafael that are unable to obtain market value for any part of their property. | |
97. | Moreover, the RV Park has few, if any, mobilehomes only recreational type vehicles, which may be moved in and out of the park easily. 11/5/02 at 67:16-24; 4/11/07 Tr at 391:18- 392:17. The RV Park also provides many fewer amenities than those available at Contempo Marin. 4/11/07 Tr at 391:18- 393:2. Consequently, MHC is uniquely affected by the Citys Ordinance. No other landowner in San Rafael suffers a burden that is remotely comparable. | |
98. | Nor has the City proffered a basis for singling out MHC to bear this burden. The affordability of housing is a market- wide problem; it is not attributable to Contempo Marin, the sole property made to bear the burden of law cost housing in San Rafael. Housing prices are set by market-wide forces, not the unilateral decisions of real estate providers. 4/24/07 Tr at 467:21-468:10. None of the Citys affordable housing policies other than the Ordinance here imposes a similar burden on other San Rafael property owners. 4/24/2007 Tr at 520:19-521:24. | |
99. | The Citys expert Ken Baar conceded that Contempo Marin has not contributed disproportionately to the problem of affordable housing in San Rafael. 4/24/07 Tr at 516:19-517:3. To the contrary, absent rent regulations, mobilehomes constitute an affordable housing choice because they reduce |
32
the capital required to acquire a single family home. 4/24/07 Tr at 516:19-517:3. Mobilehomes are produced at roughly half the cost per square foot of stick built homes and do not require tenants to purchase the land upon which the mobilehome sits. City Trial Ex BC at 112; 11/21/02 Tr at 95:12-96:18. | ||
100. | The City has placed a disproportionate burden on MHC not only by imposing the Ordinance but also by enacting a special zoning ordinance that designates Contempo Marin as a mobilehome park, rendering it commercially impracticable for MHC to change the use of its land. 4/11/07 Tr at 294:14- 298:4. | |
101. | The Citys General Plan 2000 established a specific goal of implementing the mobilehome rent control ordinance and developing a specialized zoning district to ensure preservation of the Contempo Marin Mobilehome Park. 4/9/07 Tr at 169:14-170:5, 229:7-12. | |
102. | It is immaterial that the Ordinance technically applies to two landowners. MHC has nonetheless been singled out. The relevant class for comparing treatment or allocation of any burden in a takings analysis is that of the class of persons disturbed by the lack of affordable housing presumably all of society and the group of people available to remedy that problem. Cienega Gardens, 331 F3d at 1339. | |
103. | MHCs operation within a regulated industry does not alter this fact. See Wash Legal Foundation v Legal Found of Wash, 271 F3d 835, 861 (9th Cir 2001) (remarking that the character of the government action is best viewed in the context of the industry it regulates in concluding that statutes taking |
33
interest from lawyer client trust accounts was constitutional in part because lawyers constitute a heavily regulated industry). The Ordinance at issue here is atypical; it imposes a virtually unique burden on MHC. | ||
104. | The magnitude of the Ordinances economic impact on MHC, the degree to which the Ordinance interferes with MHCs reasonable investment-backed expectations and the character of the Citys conduct all support a finding that the Ordinance is functionally equivalent to an unconstitutional taking that singles out MHC to bear a public burden that, in all fairness and justice, should be borne by the public as a whole. See Penn Central Transp Co v City of New York, 438 US 104, 124 (1978) (internal quotations omitted). | |
105. | Accordingly, the application of the Ordinance to Contempo Marin gives rise to a regulatory taking under the standards set forth in Penn Central. |
106. | The Takings Clause of the Fifth Amendment of the United States Constitution states, in relevant part, Nor shall private property be taken for public use, without just compensation. US Const Amend V. The Takings Clause applies to the states through the Fourteenth Amendment. See, for example, Dolan v City of Tigard, 512 US 374, 383-84 (1984). | |
107. | [I]t is only the takings purpose, and not its mechanics, * * * that matters in determining public use. Kelo v City of New London, 545 US 469, 482 (2005), quoting Hawaii Housing Authority v Midkiff, 467 US 229, 244 (1984). |
34
108. | For more than a century, [Supreme Court] public use jurisprudence has wisely eschewed rigid formulas and intrusive scrutiny in favor of affording legislatures broad latitude in determining what public needs justify the use of the takings power. Kelo, 545 US at 483. | |
109. | Without exception, the Supreme Court has defined [public purpose] broadly reflecting a longstanding policy of deference to legislative judgments in this field. Kelo, 545 US at 480. | |
110. | [I]f a legislature, state or federal, determines there are substantial reasons for an exercise of the taking power, courts must defer to its determination that the taking will serve a public use. Midkiff, 467 US at 244. | |
111. | Viewed as a whole, [Supreme Court] jurisprudence has recognized that the needs of society have varied between different parts of the Nation, just as they have evolved over time in response to changed circumstances. Our earliest cases in particular embodied a strong theme of federalism, emphasizing the great respect that we owe to state legislatures and state courts in discerning local public needs. Kelo, 545 US at 482, citing Hairston v Danville & Western R Co, 208 US 598, 606-07 (1908). | |
112. | When the legislatures purpose is legitimate and its means are not irrational, our cases make clear that empirical debates over the wisdom of takings no less than debates over the wisdom of other kinds of socioeconomic legislation are not to be carried out in the federal courts. Kelo, 545 US at |
35
488, quoting Midkiff, 467 US at 242 (internal quotations omitted). | ||
113. | The Ninth Circuit has held that mobile home rent control ordinances are legitimate if their stated legislative purposes are to alleviate hardship created by rapidly escalating rents; to protect owners investments in their mobile homes; to equalize the bargaining position of park owners and tenants; and to protect residents from unconscionable and coercive changes in rental rates. Levald, Inc v City of Palm Desert, 998 F2d 680, 690 (9th Cir 1993). | |
114. | While the Supreme Court has not elaborated on the standards for determining what constitutes a legitimate state interest[,] * * * [it has] made clear * * * that a broad range of governmental purposes are legitimate. Nollan, 483 US at 834. | |
115. | An attempt to define [the police powers] reach or trace its outer limits is fruitless, for each case must turn on its own facts. The definition is essentially the product of legislative determinations addressed to the purposes of government, purposes neither abstractly nor historically capable of complete definition. Subject to specific constitutional limitations, when the legislature has spoken, the public interest has been declared in terms well-nigh conclusive. In such cases the legislature, not the judiciary, is the main guardian of the public needs to be served by social legislation * * *. This principle admits of no exception merely because the power of eminent domain is involved. Berman, 348 US at 32 (internal citations omitted). |
36
116. | A city, however, would no doubt be forbidden from taking * * * land for the purpose of conferring a private benefit on a particular private party. Kelo, 545 US at 477, citing Midkiff, 467 US 229 at 245 (A purely private taking could not withstand the scrutiny of the public use requirement; it would serve no legitimate purpose of government and would thus be void.). | |
117. | The Supreme Court has further explained that it has long been accepted that the sovereign may not take the property of A for the sole purpose of transferring it to another private party B, even though A is paid just compensation. On the other hand, it is equally clear that a State may transfer property from one private party to another if future use by the public is the purpose of the taking * * *. Kelo, 545 US at 477. | |
118. | Nor may a city be allowed to take property under the mere pretext of a public purpose, when its actual purpose was to bestow a private benefit. Kelo, 545 US at 477. | |
119. | The Supreme Court, however, has rejected the contention that the mere fact that the State immediately transferred the properties to private individuals upon condemnation somehow diminished the public character of the taking. Kelo, 545 US at 482. | |
120. | Justice Kennedy, who joined the Kelo majority opinion in its entirety, issued a concurrence in which he wrote that [a] court applying rational-basis review under the Public Use Clause should strike down a taking that, by a clear showing, is intended to favor a particular private party, with only |
37
incidental or pretextual public benefits. Id at 491. Justice Kennedy derived this rule from two Equal Protection cases in which the Court proclaimed that [a] legitimate state interest must encompass the interests of members of the disadvantaged class and the community at large, as well as the direct interests of the members of the favored class. It must have a purpose or goal independent of the direct effect of the legislation * * *. Cleburne v Cleburne Living Center, Inc, 473 US 432, 452 n4 (1985) (Stevens concurring). | ||
121. | A court confronted with a plausible accusation of impermissible favoritism to private parties should treat the objection as a serious one and review the record to see if it has merit, though with the presumption that the governments actions were reasonable and intended to serve a public purpose. Kelo, 545 US at 491 (Kennedy concurring). | |
122. | The Kelo court found that the taking at issue in the case satisfied the public use requirement because it involved a carefully considered development plan that lacked evidence of an illegitimate purpose (such as a purpose to benefit Pfizer or another private entity). Id at 478 & n6. Indeed, the majority noted, the identities of the private entities who would benefit were not known when the plan was adopted. It is, of course, difficult to accuse the government of having taken As property to benefit the private interests of B when the identity of B was unknown. Id at 478 n6. | |
123. | Justice Kennedy noted approvingly that the trial courts conclusion was based on extensive fact-finding: |
38
Id at 491-92 (citations omitted). | ||
124. | To succeed on this claim, MHC must prove by a preponderance of the evidence that the circumstances surrounding the Ordinances enactment make clear that the proffered public purposes asserted as justification for the Ordinance are palpably without reasonable foundation, see Midkiff, 467 US at 240, or that the City imposed the Ordinance under the mere pretext of a public purpose, when its actual purpose was to bestow a private benefit, see Kelo, 545 US at 478. | |
125. | As explained, the court finds that the Ordinance creates a premium in subsequent sales of mobilehomes in parks subject to its regulation. This premium reflects the capitalized value of the expected privilege of paying increasingly below-market rents and the ability to sell that benefit to future buyers. See Yee, 503 US at 526 (stating that due to the unusual economic relationship between park owners and mobile home owners[,] * * * any reduction in the rent for a mobile home pad causes a corresponding increase in the value of a mobile |
39
home, because the mobile home owner now owns, in addition to a mobile home, the right to occupy a pad at a rent below the value that would be set by the free market). | ||
126. | The payment of this premium is no different from the transfer of rental rights along with key money in regulation of apartment rents, as both are mechanisms by which current residents may capture the economic value of the regulation and thereby deprive the intended beneficiaries of any advantage. See MHC Trial Ex 103, 104, 341; 11/19/02 Tr at 33-35, 52-55; Yee, 503 US at 530 (explaining that because apartment tenants do not sell anything to their successors and are often prohibited from charging key money, * * * a typical rent control statute will transfer wealth from the landlord to the incumbent tenant and all future tenants). | |
127. | The premium created by the Ordinance, on the other hand, allowing current mobilehome owners to capture the monetized value of below-market rent ultimately vitiates the connection between the Ordinance and the goals it was intended to further. | |
128. | As part of its inquiry into whether the City imposed the Ordinance under the mere pretext of a public purpose, the court must examine whether there is any connection between the operative provisions and the asserted purposes of the Ordinance. Nollan v Calif Coastal Commn, 483 US 825, 837 (1987); Yee, 503 US at 530. | |
129. | In this case, the creation and transfer of the premium weighs against a finding that the operative provisions of the Ordinance bear relation to the public goals it is meant to |
40
further. See Yee, 503 US at 526, citing Hirsch & Hirsch, Legal-Economic Analysis of Rent Controls in a Mobile Home Context: Placement Values and Vacancy Decontrol, 35 UCLA L Rev 399, 430-31 (1988). | ||
130. | The City advances three purportedly legitimate governmental interests furthered by the Ordinance: (1) protection of mobilehome owner equity; (2) protection of fixed-income residents and (3) creation of more affordable housing. Assuming without deciding that all three interests, as a general matter, are legitimate state interests, see City of Monterey, 526 US at 732 (Scalia concurring), the court discusses each in turn. |
131. | The City contends that without the Ordinance and in particular vacancy control mobilehome park owners like MHC would be able to extract a portion of the mobilehome owners equity in their homes upon sale of the mobilehome. An increased rental rate upon transfer of ownership makes it more difficult for current owners to sell their homes combined with the general impracticality of moving mobilehomes and the scarcity of available pads in surrounding areas mean that the park owner could force existing tenants to sell the coach-in-place at distress-sale prices. Adamson, 854 F Supp at 1493. | |
132. | The City bases this argument on the reasoning in Adamson. The Adamson court noted that the price at which a mobilehome owner can sell her mobilehome is related to the lease that will be charged to a new owner. Id (From the standpoint of a |
41
prospective buyer with a set amount of money to pay for a coach, the lower the rent he must pay, the more money he will have left over to dedicate to the mortgage on the coach.). | ||
133. | The Adamson court then noted that the price a new owner would be willing to pay is based in part on the placement value of the mobilehome. Id at 1488-89. The court then noted that even though mobilehomes depreciate, prices obtained by mobilehome owners upon sale of their mobilehomes have increased. Id. The court reasoned from this that the placement value makes up a substantial, if not the dominant, element of the purchase price of a coach upon a change in tenancy. Id. This results in the mobilehome owners and the park owners wsharing in the placement value upon a sale of the mobilehome. Id. | |
134. | The Adamson court then concluded that the historical arrangement whereby mobilehome owners seemed to capture a portion of the placement value created an expectation that they will be able to substantially recoup that investment upon the sale of the coach. Id. This expectation in turn created a property right to a portion of the placement value. Id. | |
135. | Notwithstanding the district courts considered ruling in Adamson, this court concludes that the Citys argument fails for two reasons. First, the mobilehome owners equity in their mobilehomes is limited to the salvage value of the mobilehome. There is simply no legal authority for the proposition that a tenant has any interest in the placement value of the mobilehome. It is axiomatic that [t]he effect of [a] lease is to carve an estate for years out of [the |
42
lessors ownership of an estate in fee simple in the premises] and to leave in the lessor a reversion in fee simple. Cornelius J Moynihan, Introduction to the Law of Real Property § 8 at 91 (2d ed 1988). While a lessee may possess an interest in the increased value of his leasehold as a result of an increase in the value of the estate during his tenancy, the court is unaware of any authority that permits a tenant to transform any part of the lessors reversionary interests into his own upon the termination of the leasehold. | ||
136. | Given the nature of an interest in fee simple, the opposite is true. See Hirsch & Hirsch, 35 UCLA L Rev at 429 (emphasizing that placement value is not equity belonging to the tenant; the mobile home coach owners equity would be the value of the coach less encumbrances on the coach). The coach is considered to be the tenants personal property; as the Citys own expert testified, the coachs attachment to the site does not constitute any investment in the location value of the lessors reversionary fee simple interest. See 11/25/02 Tr at 141:4-142:6; 2 Nichols on Eminent Domain § 5.03[5][a] at 5-151 (rev 3d ed 2000). | |
137. | Accordingly, the mobilehome owners only equity in their mobilehomes is the salvage value of their units, which is the replacement value minus the pull-out costs. The mobilehome owners leasehold interest is analogous to the leasehold interest of an apartment dweller. An apartment dweller who confronts a raise in rent beyond his capability or willingness to pay can relocate apartments. Such relocation will involve the pull-out costs of moving his or her belongings. |
43
Likewise, a mobilehome owner seeking to sell the coach in-place but unable to do so because of the park owners intent to increase the pad rental beyond any prospective mobilehome purchasers willingness to pay confronts pull-out costs. The mobilehome owner may have significantly greater pull-out costs than apartment dwellers. But the magnitude of these costs does not alter the legal relationship created by the lease. | ||
138. | Because existing pad lessees do not have any legally recognized property interest in the location value of their mobilehomes, the Ordinance does not serve to protect an interest legitimately owned by a pad lessee in the location value of the pad. | |
139. | Second, mobilehome park owners have no mechanism nor any incentive to extract equity from the mobilehome owners. The City contends that the existence of pull-out costs gives MHC (and other mobilehome park owners) leverage that can be used to appropriate the equity that mobilehome owners possess in their mobilehomes. As described above, the mobilehome owners only equity is the salvage value of their mobilehomes, which is the replacement value less the pull-out cost. The City envisions a situation in which a park owner attempts to charge such a high rent that a mobilehome owner would be required to sell his mobilehome at below its salvage value. In such a situation, the mobilehome owner would merely refuse to sell the mobilehome at that price. The mobilehome owner could move from the park and recover from MHC the salvage value, thus avoiding the pull-out costs. Because the mobilehome owners equity interest does not include any locational value in the |
44
pad except as a pad lease provides, that interest needs no protection and the Ordinance cannot find constitutional rescue on this purported public interest. | ||
140. | In fact, as evidenced by the analysis in Adamson, park owners have an incentive to provide a benefit to outgoing mobilehome owners rather than extract equity from them. Without vacancy control, the park owner may charge a new tenant more than the previous tenant. Discounting transactional costs associated with setting up a new lease, a park owner would, therefore, prefer new tenants to old tenants because new tenants will pay more. Additionally, a new tenant who must provide a mobilehome will have to pay transportation costs. These costs take away money that could otherwise be used to pay a higher pad rent. Accordingly, in order to induce old tenants to move and to leave their mobilehomes in place, a park owner may choose to share some of the placement value with the outgoing tenant. |
141. | The Ordinance fails to create more affordable housing for incoming tenants. The court has found that the Ordinance creates a premium representing the capitalized value of transferable below-market rent. This means that incoming tenants will not receive any benefit from the rent control provisions. The benefit of a lower rent will be entirely offset by the need to pay a higher capital outlay upfront. Rather than create more affordable housing, the Ordinance creates less affordable housing. |
45
142. | Vacancy control also fails to create more affordable housing for incumbent tenants. The vacancy control ordinance of 1989 does not influence the current rent that a tenant must pay. This rate is regulated by the 1999 Amendments, which set the rent at a base rate plus 75 percent of the CPI-C. Accordingly, vacancy control does not influence the rent that the current tenant must pay. | |
143. | As explained, vacancy control provides a one-time wealth transfer from the park owners to the mobilehome owners. This transfer occurs upon the enactment of the vacancy control provision, but the cash value of the transfer is usually not realized until the mobilehome is sold to a new tenant. | |
144. | To be sure, the premium transfer makes housing more affordable for the incumbent mobilehome owner, but only when he sells his mobilehome, not during his ownership. The Ordinance fails to fulfill the Citys broader objective of making housing more affordable. The incumbent mobilehome owner is under no obligation to reinvest any part of the wealth transfer into housing; rather, the vacancy control provision has merely given the incumbent tenant a corpus of money that can be used for any purpose. The City made no showing whatsoever that the premium realized by the mobilehome owner is re-invested to create new housing in San Rafael. | |
145. | Vacancy control tends to make housing less affordable for another reason. Adding vacancy control to the existing rent control provisions makes creating mobilehome parks less profitable. All other things remaining equal, fewer investors will create mobilehome parks. This will increase scarcity and |
46
drive up the cost of existing plots, a conclusion borne out by the evidence here. See 4/24/07 Tr at 506:6-507:5; MHC Trial Ex 392, 393. | ||
146. | Vacancy control also reduces the benefits and increases the costs of mobilehome ownership. The distinctive advantage of mobilehome ownership is that the pad lessee avoids the initial capital outlay required to own the ground upon which the mobilehome sits, notwithstanding the higher interest rates required for mobilehome financing as compared to stick built housing. See MHC Trial Ex 105 at 15-17 (finding that interest rates range from 10.44 percent to 15.24 percent). Vacancy control nullifies this advantage. A new mobilehome owner under vacancy control pays a much more substantial initial capital outlay (in return for lower lease payments), and must do so at a high interest rate. 4/24/07 Tr at 468:11-469:17. As described above, the premium obtained by the incumbent mobilehome owner exactly cancels out the value of the future decreased rent payments. It does, however, change the risks and investment associated with mobilehome ownership, requiring a greater capital investment, with its attendant risks of default to the incoming tenant. |
147. | The Ordinance fails to protect fixed-income residents, including senior citizens. As noted above, the court finds that the Ordinance does not make housing more affordable. The creation of a premium cancels out the expected pecuniary benefits of below-market rent that incoming tenants would |
47
receive. To the extent that housing is not made more affordable, low and fixed-income individuals cannot be benefitted. | ||
148. | As noted above, by requiring incoming tenants to make a much more substantial capital outlay, vacancy control erases the benefits and increases the costs of mobilehome ownership. This problem is particularly pronounced for fixed-income individuals. Mobilehome ownership is attractive to fixed- income individuals because it only requires a lower initial cash outlay. Because vacancy control requires incoming tenants to trade a larger initial capital outlay for reduced rents later, it reduces this benefit. Accordingly, vacancy control frustrates rather than furthers the interests of fixed-income individuals. |
149. | The City puts forward numerous cases that purportedly compel the conclusion that the Ordinance passes constitutional muster. The City argues that because its Ordinance serves the same policies as many similar ordinances that have been found constitutional, the Ordinance must be upheld. But a legislative enactment cannot find refuge in its purported purposes, no matter how noble or valid, if it also effects a constitutional injury. The court must look to the regulations operation, not just its aim, to ascertain its true nature. | |
150. | The City further argues that because the Ordinances administrative petition process allows for actual rent |
48
increases to be any amount greater than the increase automatically provided for under the base formula, the existence of a premium would depend on how the Ordinance is applied. According to the City, the Ordinances administrative petition process creates the possibility that actual rent increases will keep up with inflation so that no premium in fact is created. | ||
151. | Although the Ordinance at issue here provides a mechanism, on its face, through which park owners may petition for rent increases beyond the base formula, the pertinent question is not whether rent increases under the Ordinance may theoretically keep pace with inflation by way of the administrative petition process. Rather the question is whether the mere enactment of the Ordinance has created a premium that effects a transfer of wealth to existing mobilehome owners at the time of amendment for which MHC has not been compensated and which fails to serve a public purpose. The court finds that the Ordinance does so. | |
152. | The court finds that the proffered public purposes asserted as justifications for the Ordinance are palpably without reasonable foundation, in spite of the longstanding policy of deference to legislative judgments in this field. Kelo, 545 US at 480. MHCs collection of economic evidence raises a strong inference that the City imposed the Ordinance under the mere pretext of a public purpose. This inference is confirmed by the evidence with respect to Contempo Marin. | |
153. | The City has persistently supported the tenants desire to convert the Contempo Marin to a tenant-owned community. In |
49
1991, City of San Rafael Mayor Al Boro sent a letter to the tenants of Contempo Marin in which he sought the tenants support in an upcoming election and specifically promised the tenants that he would continue working with [the residents] in [their] efforts to acquire ownership of the park. A Boro Dep Tr at 31:8-32:18. | ||
154. | Soon after, on March 18, 1991, the City passed a resolution [s]upporting preservation of the Contempo Marin Mobile Home Park and supporting purchase of the Park by residents, in which the City specifically resolved that it strongly supports the preservation of the Contempo Marin Mobile Home Park as a low and moderate income housing project and supports its purchase by Park tenants * * *. A Boro Dep Tr at 33:11- 34:9. | |
155. | To assess the feasibility of these plans, the City requested a study to determine whether or not it would be financially feasible to purchase the park or to use the Citys powers of eminent domain to acquire the park. 4/9/07 Tr at 185:14- 186:8; 11/1/02 Tr at 15:22-16:21; 4/9/07 Tr at 192:18-24 (concerning appraisal of Richard Brabant); 4/9/07 Tr at 195:21-197:4 (City council members urge the pursuit of purchase for residents). | |
156. | More significantly, the very idea of reducing the CPI-C and modifying the capital expenditure recoupment provisions in 1999 originated with the tenants, not the City or City staff. 4/9/07 Tr at 193:16-194:3. | |
157. | The Citys revocation of the settlement agreement in this case at the behest of the tenants, 4/11/07 Tr at 297:8-298:4, is |
50
yet another instance of the Citys blatant efforts to confer a private benefit to particular, favored private entities, Kelo, 545 US at 490, namely the Contempo Marin tenants. | ||
158. | Because the assertion of a public purpose is pretextual and without reasonable basis and because the Ordinance has been amended and enforced for the singular purpose of transferring the value of land from one private party to another, the Citys enforcement of the Ordinance constitutes a taking not for public use and, therefore, constitutes a private taking. |
159. | The Due Process Clause of the Fourteenth Amendment provides that no state shall deprive any person of life, liberty, or property, without due process of law. US Const Amend XIV. Substantive due process protects individuals from arbitrary and unreasonable government action that deprives any person of life, liberty or property. Kawaoka v City of Arroyo Grande, 17 F3d 1227, 1234 (9th Cir 1994). | |
160. | To establish a substantive due process violation, the governments action must have been clearly arbitrary and unreasonable, having no substantial relation to the public health, safety, morals, or general welfare. Sinaloa Lake Owners v City of Simi Valley, 882 F2d 1398, 1407 (9th Cir 1989), quoting Village of Euclid v Ambler Realty Co, 272 US 365, 395 (1926). | |
161. | The challengers burden to show that a statute is arbitrary and irrational is extremely high. Kawaoka. 17 F3d at 1234, |
51
citing Del Monte Dunes v Monterey, 920 F2d 1496, 1508 (9th Cir 1990). | ||
162. | In a substantive due process challenge, [courts] do not require that the Citys legislative acts actually advance its stated purposes, but instead look to whether the governmental body could have had no legitimate reason for its decision. Kawaoka. 17 F3d at 1234 (9th Cir 1994), quoting Levald, 998 F2d at 690 (internal quotations omitted). | |
163. | Before Lingle, 544 US at 548, the Ninth Circuit concluded that a deprivation of property cannot be challenged via substantive due process. Armendariz v Penman, 75 F3d 1311 (9th Cir 1996); Ventura, 371 F3d at 1054; see also Crown Point Development v City of Sun Valley, 2006 WL 288392 at *2 (D Idaho Feb 6, 2006), revd, 506 F3d 851 (9th Cir 2007) ([T]his Court applies the current Ninth Circuit law and finds the complaint should be dismissed as the law of this circuit does not allow substantive due process claims * * * when the interest at stake is real property.) | |
164. | Yet Lingle plainly suggests the availability of a substantive due process challenge to a regulatory taking. See Lingle, 544 US at 540 (We conclude that [the substantially advances] formula prescribes an inquiry in the nature of a due process, not a takings, test * * *.) . See also id (noting that prob[ing] the regulations underlying validity is logically prior to and distinct from the question whether a regulation effects a taking, for the Takings Clause presupposes that the government has acted in pursuit of a valid public purpose). |
52
165. | More significantly, Lingle undercuts the Ninth Circuits basis for barring substantive due process challenges to deprivations of property. The rationale for this bar was that claims should rely on the explicit textual sources of constitutional protection, if available, such as the takings clause, rather than the more generalized notion of substantive due process. Armendariz, 75 F3d at 1324. But Lingle held that challenges concerning the means-ends relationship of a statute do not implicate the Takings Clause. 544 US at 542. Hence, after Lingle, there is no explicit text for assessing whether a regulation is effective in achieving a legitimate public purpose; only the Due Process Clause remains. See also Blaesser & Weinstein, Federal Land Use Law & Litigation § 2:11 (noting that, after Lingle, [i]f a land use regulation furthers no public purpose whatsoever then, although just compensation is no longer available under the Fifth Amendment, the failure of the regulation to substantially advance any legitimate public purpose in violation of due process * * * would give rise to a cause of action for damages under 42 USC § 1983). | |
166. | Accordingly, the court concludes that after Lingle, Armendariz and its progeny no longer preclude a substantive due process challenge to deprivations of property. This reading of the law has been confirmed by a panel of the Ninth Circuit subsequent to the trial herein. Crown Point Development, Inc v City of Sun Valley, 506 F3d 851, 856 (9th Cir 2007). | |
167. | For judicial scrutiny of price-control regulation under the Due Process Clause, the standard * * * is well established: |
53
Price control is unconstitutional * * * if arbitrary, discriminatory, or demonstrably irrelevant to the policy the legislature is free to adopt * * *. Pennell v San Jose, 485 US 1, 11 (1988), citing Permian Basin Area Rate Cases, 390 US 747, 769-70 (1968), quoting Nebbia v New York, 291 US 502, 539 (1934). | ||
168. | In Pennell v San Jose, plaintiffs challenged a rent control statute that required a hearing in the event that a tenant challenged a raise in rent in excess of 8 percent per year. 485 US 1, 5 (1988). The statute required the hearing officer to take into account the hardship that the proposed rental increase would impose on the tenant. Id. The Court rejected a substantive due process challenge, finding that a legitimate and rational goal of price or rate regulation is the protection of consumer welfare. Id at 13, citing Permian Basin, 390 US at 770; FPC v Hope Natural Gas Co, 320 US 591, 610-12 (1944). Because the rent control statute in Pennell provided a hearing that balanced a number of factors, including the history of the premises, the landlords costs and the market for comparable housing, the Court concluded that the scheme represented a rational attempt to accommodate the conflicting interests of protecting tenants from burdensome rent increases while at the same time ensuring that landlords are guaranteed a fair return on their investment. Id. | |
169. | The Ninth Circuit in Levald, Inc v City of Palm Desert, 998 F2d 680 (9th Cir 1993), held that [o]rdinances survive a substantive due process challenge if they [are] designed to |
54
accomplish an objective within the governments police power, and if a rational relationship exist[s] between the provisions and purpose of the ordinances. 998 F2d at 690, citing Boone v Redevelopment Agency of City of San Jose, 841 F2d 886, 892 (9th Cir 1988) (emphasis in original). The plaintiff in Levald, a mobilehome landowner, challenged the constitutionality of a vacancy and rent control ordinance similar to the one at issue here. The Levald court rejected the owners substantive due process challenge, concluding that a rational legislator could have believed that the rent control ordinance would further the stated goals, at least insofar as the purpose is to protect existing tenants. Id at 690. The Levald court specifically rejected the owners argument that the ordinance failed rational basis review because it transferred rent premiums from landlords to tenants: |
Id (citation omitted) (alterations in original). | ||
170. | The Ninth Circuit reached a similar conclusion in Richardson v City and County of Honolulu, 124 F3d 1150, 1164 (9th Cir 1997), which did not involve mobilehomes, but otherwise deals with the same economic premium theory advanced by MHC here. In a substantive due process challenge, we do not require |
55
that the Citys legislative acts actually advance its stated purposes, but instead look to whether the governmental body could have had no legitimate reason for its decision. * * * [W]e hold that the landowners cannot meet the burden of showing irrationality. Richardson, 124 F3d at 1162 (internal citation omitted) (emphasis in original). | ||
171. | The evidence adduced by MHC offers no grounds for distinguishing the Ninth Circuits decision in Levald, Inc v City of Palm Desert, 998 F2d 680, 690 (9th Cir 1993). | |
172. | The Supreme Courts decision in Lingle v Chevron USA, Inc, 544 US 528 (2005), appears to counsel against the deferential review mandated by Levald. The Court observed that prob[ing] the regulations underlying validity is logically prior to and distinct from the question whether a regulation effects a taking, for the Takings Clause presupposes that the government has acted in pursuit of a valid public purpose. Lingle, 544 US at 543. The Court further emphasized that a regulation that fails to serve any legitimate governmental objective may be so arbitrary or irrational that it runs afoul of the Due Process Clause. Id at 542. See also Steven J Eagle, Property Tests, Due Process Tests and Regulatory Takings Jurisprudence, 2007 BYU L Rev 899, 957 (In Lingle v Chevron USA, the Court did not repudiate its pronouncement * * * that a regulation does not pass muster if it does not substantially advance legitimate state interests. To the contrary, it ratified that formulation not as a takings test but rather as a test to determine if landowners have been accorded due process.) (quotation marks and footnotes omitted). |
56
173. | Justice Kennedy, who joined the Lingle opinion in its entirety, issued a concurrence in which he noted that [the Lingle] decision does not foreclose the possibility that a regulation might be so arbitrary or irrational as to violate due process. The failure of a regulation to accomplish a stated or obvious objective would be relevant to that inquiry. Lingle, 544 US at 548 (Kennedy concurring) (citations omitted). | |
174. | The discussion in Lingle of due process scrutiny remains dicta, however, because the Court had no occasion to assess plaintiffs due process claim as it had voluntarily dismissed the claim prior to the Courts review of the case. Furthermore, a recent panel decision of the Ninth Circuit appears to indicate that the court of appeals is reluctant to depart from the line of authority, albeit on a different set of facts from this case. See Equity Lifestyle Properties v San Luis Obispo, 505 F3d 860 (9th Cir 2007). As such, it would be inappropriate to construe the foregoing language in Lingle as overturning long-standing Ninth Circuit precedent sub silentio. | |
175. | Accordingly, the court concludes that the challenged Ordinance does not violate the Due Process Clause of the United States Constitution. |
57
1. | Under Williamson County Regional Planning Commission v Hamilton Bank, 473 US 172, 186-87 (1985), a takings claim is ripe when: (1) the government entity charged with implementing the regulations has reached a final decision regarding the application of the regulations to the property at issue, and (2) the plaintiff seek[s] compensation through the procedures the State has provided, unless doing so would be futile. See also Ventura Mobilehome Communities Owners Assn v City of San Buenaventura, 371 F3d 1046, 1053 (9th Cir 2004) (request for capital improvement pass-through may suffice for exhaustion purposes). | |
2. | The first prong of the Williamson ripeness analysis only pertains to as-applied takings claims. Facial claims, by definition, derive from the ordinances enactment, not any implementing action on the part of the government authorities, and therefore do not require a final decision. Ventura, 371 F3d at 1052. The exhaustion requirement applies to both facial and as-applied takings claims. | |
3. | A premium-based takings claim is a challenge to the regulation on its face, not as it is applied. Richardson, 124 F3d at 1165, citing Carson Harbor, 37 F3d at 474 n5; Levald, 998 F2d at 686 (existence of premium is relevant only to a facial, not an as-applied, regulatory challenge because [i]t is not the particular application of the statute that gives rise to |
58
the premium; the premium arises solely from the existence of the statute itself). | ||
4. | With respect to MHCs substantive due process and private takings claims, only the final decision requirement applies. The Supreme Court has stated that if a government action is found to be impermissible for instance because it fails to meet the public use requirement or is so arbitrary as to violate due process that is the end of the inquiry. No amount of compensation can authorize such action. Lingle, 544 US at 543; see also Armendariz, 75 F3d at 1321 n5 (Because a private taking cannot be constitutional even if compensated, a plaintiff alleging such a taking would not need to seek compensation in state proceedings before filing a federal takings claim.). | |
5. | The final decision requirement ensures that a concrete case or controversy exists, as [a] court cannot determine whether a regulation goes too far unless it knows how far the regulation goes. Palazzolo, 533 US at 621-22, quoting MacDonald, Sommer & Frates v Yolo County, 477 US 340, 348 (1986). See also Palazzolo, 533 US at 620 (remarking that the final decision prong of Williamson embodies the important principle that a landowner may not establish a taking before a land-use authority has the opportunity, using its own reasonable procedures, to decide and explain the reach of a challenged regulation). |
59
6. | [R]esort beyond the initial decision-maker is not necessary to fulfill the final decision prong of the ripeness analysis. Hacienda Valley Mobile Estates v City of Morgan Hill, 353 F3d 651, 657 (9th Cir 2003). | |
7. | Once it becomes clear that the * * * permissible uses of the property are known to a reasonable degree of certainty, a takings claim is likely to have ripened. Palazzolo, 533 US at 620; see also Carson Harbor Village, Ltd v City of Carson, 353 F3d 824, 826-27 (9th Cir 2004) (final decision prong requires giving the government the opportunity to grant any variances or waivers allowed by the law). | |
8. | The final decision requirement does not oblige MHC to file for a discretionary rent increase because of the settlement reached by the parties. Under the settlement agreement, the City agreed to initiate amendments to the Ordinance that would eliminate vacancy control, Doc #23, Ex1, §2, but then the City reversed course and formally declined to eliminate vacancy control. Through these events, MHC obtained a final decision from the City notwithstanding MHCs failure to request a discretionary rent increase after 1999. The Citys conduct throughout the dispute makes plain its intention to subject MHC to the Ordinance, a fact underscored by Citys unwillingness to eliminate vacancy control pursuant to the parties settlement agreement in 2002. | |
9. | MHCs Penn Central claim must also satisfy the exhaustion requirement of Williamson County unless doing so would be |
60
futile. Under the Just Compensation Clause of the Fifth Amendment, a landowner whose land is taken by the government is entitled to the market value of the property at the time of the taking contemporaneously paid in money. Olsen v United States, 292 US 246, 255 (1934); Palazzolo, 533 US at 625 (When a taking has occurred, under accepted condemnation principles the owners damages will be based upon the propertys fair market value.). | ||
10. | As this court found in its December 5, 2006 order, see Doc #486, MHC has exhausted remedies in seeking an inverse condemnation remedy in 1996. | |
11. | In 1996, MHC filed a rent increase petition related to capita] expenditures it made for the park lagoon transfer station. MHC Trial Ex 346. After an initial dispute regarding the appropriate amount of the rent increase, MHC reached a settlement with residents for the first phase of the capital expenditure. Yet a dispute arose concerning the second phase rent increase, which was resolved informally by an arbitrator the parties had dealt with previously. The arbitrator sided with the tenants and declined to recommend that MHC receive the full amount of the rent increase it requested. | |
12. | MHC appealed the opinion to the City council. MHC Trial Ex 312. But the City refused to accept the appeal on the ground that the arbitrator in the second dispute had been acting as a mediator, not an arbitrator. MHC Trial Ex 314; 4/9/07 Tr at 236:6-237:2. |
61
13. | Next, the tenants sued MHC for attempting to collect the capital expenditure increase permitted under the second phase of its settlement agreement. MHC cross-claimed and asserted inverse condemnation against the City. In connection with that cross-claim, the City demurred and held that MHC had waived any right to be heard on the merits because it did not take a writ of mandate from the Citys refusal to hear its appeal of the non-binding decision from the mediator. The state courts agreed with the City in a final opinion issued on July 15, 2005. MHC Trial Ex 332; 4/11/07 Tr at 284:14-287:7. | |
14. | In the end, MHC spent almost ten years in litigation only to recoup about one third of the capital expenditures it was seeking to recover, 4/11/07 Tr at 276:5-288:4; there is no further recourse on the merits of its fair return petition and state inverse condemnation petition. MHC Trial Ex 314; 4/9/07 Tr at 237:3-238:4. | |
15. | These events demonstrate that the Citys tactics deprive MHC of the ability to obtain judicial review of administrative decisions. The City does so by refusing to issue an administrative decision from which MHC may appeal and then citing MHCs failure to seek mandamus relief as a means of precluding further judicial review of the merits of MHCs claims. | |
16. | The record makes clear that the Citys discretionary rent increase process does not provide a remedy to cure an impermissibly low rental increase. |
62
17. | In Kavanau v Santa Monica Rent Control Board, 16 Cal 4th 761, 782, 66 Cal Rptr 2d 672, 941 P2d 85 (1997), the California Supreme Court held that a remedy for the due process violation [of an unconstitutional rent control ordinance], if available and adequate, obviates a finding of a taking [under the Fifth Amendment]. See also Galland v City of Clovis, 24 Cal 4th 1003, 1025 103 Cal Rptr 2d 711, 16 P3d 130 (2001) ([W]hen landlords seek section 1983 damages from allegedly confiscatory rent regulation, we hold that they must show (1) that a confiscatory rent ceiling or other rent regulation was imposed and (2) that relief via a writ of mandate and a Kavanau adjustment is inadequate.). The only alternative to the Citys procedures is a future rent increase or Kavanau adjustment under state law, which, for reasons discussed below, is likewise inadequate. 4/9/07 Tr at 239:24-240:12; 4/9/07 Tr at 182:18-21. | |
18. | California recognizes a constitutional right to receive a fair rate of return ones property. Hillsboro Properties v City of Rohnert Park, 138 Cal App 4th 379, 391 (Cal Ct App 2006), for which the exclusive remedy is a Kavanau adjustment. Hillsboro, 138 Cal App 4th at 392. A Kavanau adjustment is a prospective rent increase to enable a park owner to recoup lost rents (from tenants) sufficient to provide a fair return. |
63
19. | To satisfy Williamson County, the Kavanau adjustment must serve as a reasonable, certain and adequate provision for obtaining compensation. Williamson. 473 US at 194. | |
20. | To seek a Kavanau adjustment, a landowner must first petition for a rent adjustment before an administrative agency. If unsuccessful, the landowner may appeal to the city council and, if that appeal is unsuccessful, the landowner may seek review in state court through a writ of administrative mandamus. Then, if the state courts agree that the city council should have granted the petition, the landowner must return to the original administrative agency and file another petition requesting the agency to remedy its prior decision. 4/30/07 Tr at 868:8-870:8. The entire process takes seven years on average. 4/30/07 Tr at 870:21-871:21. In the meantime, landowners such as MHC have no way to recoup any losses stemming from the difference between the rents to which they are entitled and those being collected during the entire time this process takes place. 4/30/07 Tr at 871:22-873:22. | |
21. | As MHCs expert testified, only one landowner has succeeded in having a Kavanau adjustment granted, and that required the owner to wait nine years and yielded about half of what the owner sought in his original petition. 4/30/07 Tr at 876:3-21. | |
22. | Requiring a Kavanau remedy would be futile here, as it would remand MHC to the very administrative body the City council that has squarely rejected a resolution of this claim. The |
64
ripeness doctrine does not require a landowner to submit applications for their own sake; rather, it imposes obligations because [a] court cannot determine whether a regulation goes too far unless it knows how far the regulation goes. Palazzolo, 533 US at 620; MacDonald, 477 US at 348. | ||
23. | Moreover, the Kavanau remedy does not pass muster under Williamson County, as it fails to provide either a fair return or adequate remedy. 4/30/07 Tr at 874:9-875:2. Carson Harbor Village, Ltd v City of Carson, 353 F3d 824, 830 (9th Cir 2004) (OScannlain concurring) (noting serious concerns about the adequacy of the * * * compensation procedures established in Kavanau). As has been pointed out, a Kavanau adjustment would entail increased future pad rentals. To the extent that lessees paying these higher rentals had not received the benefit of the impermissibly depressed rentals, such lessees would be required to pay the just compensation that the City is required to pay. Carson Harbor Village, 353 F3d at 831 (OScannlain concurring). In this case, that result would be doubly injurious to lessees who moved into Contempo Marin after the effective date of the 1999 Amendments; such lessees would not only have paid the premium the Ordinance creates but they would be obligated to pay the compensation which the City is constitutionally obligated to pay. A Kavanau adjustment affords no remedy at all in these circumstances. |
65
24. | Accordingly, MHC has fully exhausted state remedies with respect to its as-applied taking claims by litigating unsuccessfully its 1996 fair return petition and by negotiating a settlement agreement with the City. Additionally, further pursuit of administrative remedies would be futile and unavailing. |
25. | The City and CMHA argue that the statute of limitations bars MHCs constitutional challenge. | |
26. | The statute of limitations is an affirmative defense, which the claimant bears the burden of proving. United States v Real Property, Titled in the Names of Godfrey Soon Bong Rang and Darrell Lee, 120 F3d 947, 949 (9th Cir 1997), citing California Sansome Co v United States Gypsum, 55 F3d 1402, 1406 (9th Cir 1995). | |
27. | All parties agree that the applicable statute of limitations in this case is one year (for § 1983 suits in California). De Anza Properties X, Ltd v County of Santa Cruz, 936 F2d 1084, 1085 (9th Cir 1991) . The parties disagree, however, whether the 1999 Amendments effected a new injury so that a new limitations period began on enactment of the 1999 Amendments. | |
28. | In general, the statute of limitations begins to run when a potential plaintiff knows or has reason to know of the asserted injury. Norco Constr, Inc v King County, 801 F2d 1143, 1146 (9th Cir 1986). |
66
29. | A facial takings claim accrues upon passage of the legislative action at issue. Levald, Inc v City of Palm Desert, 998 F2d 680, 687 (9th Cir 1993). | |
30. | An amendment to an ordinance does not constitute a different injury, creating a new limitations period, if the effect of the ordinance upon the plaintiffs has not been altered and the plaintiffs experienced substantially the same injury [under the previous ordinance] that they experienced [under the amended ordinance]. De Anza Properties X, 936 F2d at 1086. | |
31. | As explained, the 1999 Amendments altered the formula used to calculate the rent increase that could automatically be charged by a park owner. | |
32. | This modification to the Citys Ordinance deprived MHC, which purchased the park in 1994 under a substantially different regulatory regime, of its investment-backed expectations by effecting a reduction in the parks value and assuring that regulated rents remain and over time fall progressively further below fair market rents. | |
33. | The court concludes that the City and CMHA have failed to meet their burden of proving by a preponderance of the evidence that the 1999 Amendments effected substantially the same injury. Instead, the court finds the opposite to be true. As noted above, the value of Contempo Marin decreased by slightly more than $10 million as a result of the 1999 Amendments. See 11/6/02 Trial at 196:5-198:3. This reduction in land value |
67
was due to the anticipated effect of the reduced revenues caused by the modification in the automatic rent adjustment formula. Id; see also Werner Z Hirsch and Joel G Hirsch, Legal-Economic Analysis of Rent Controls in a Mobile Home Context: Placement Values and Vacancy Decontrol, 35 UCLA L Rev 399, 424 (1988) (explaining that because the reduced future income flow is capitalized into the value of the park, the immediate effect of rent control is that the value of [the park] has been reduced). Moreover, from the enactment of vacancy control in 1993 until the 1999 Amendments, the CPI-C did not increase by more than 5 percent in any year. As a result, plaintiffs did not suffer the injury that resulted from the 1999 Amendments. | ||
34. | MHCs expert testified convincingly that the 1999 Amendments materially altered the dynamic between the automatically allowed increase and the vacancy control provisions. Insofar as the alleged premium occurs because new mobilehome owners are willing to pay current tenants for the privilege of paying pad rents artificially kept below market rate, the shift away from a regime under which the rental rate increases largely keep up with inflation to one under which cumulative rent increases fall progressively further behind the overall rate of inflation means that the change in the formula enacted in 1999 constituted more than a minor amendment in the operation of the Ordinance. Rather, the Ordinance, as amended in 1999, represented a fresh injury subject to facial |
68
challenge. See also Adamson Companies v City of Malibu, 854 F Supp 1476, 1484 (CD Cal 1994) ([E]ven if each element standing alone would be constitutional, the [regulatory] scheme must fall if, taken as a whole, it exceeds constitutional bounds.). | ||
35. | De Anza Properties X, 936 F2d at 1086, is inapposite precisely because the operation of the ordinance at issue in that case did not change; only the sunset provision was modified. | |
36. | By contrast, in the case at bar, the court finds that the operation of the Ordinance was substantially altered in 1999. As a result, MHC and CMHAs statute of limitations defense fails. | |
37. | The court hastens to add that MHC may bring a timely claim based on the totality of the amended Ordinance. Provisions that were found in the predecessor Ordinance are not immunized from judicial scrutiny. The constitutionality of an ordinance can only be determined by evaluating the totality of its provisions and effects, and there is no precedent suggesting that only limited parts of an integrated regulatory scheme should be evaluated in isolation. Richards v United States, 369 US 1, 11 (1962). |
38. | The City argues that based on the De Anza litigation, MHCs takings claims must fail because they have already been adjudicated in a prior judicial proceeding. |
69
39. | The doctrine of res judicata provides that a final judgment on the merits bars further claims by parties or their privies based on the same cause of action. The application of this doctrine is central to the purpose for which civil courts have been established, the conclusive resolution of disputes within their jurisdiction. Moreover, a rule precluding parties from the contestation of matters already fully and fairly litigated conserves judicial resources and fosters reliance on judicial action by minimizing the possibility of inconsistent decisions. In re Schimmels, 127 F3d 8875, 881 (9th Cir 1997), quoting Montana v United States, 440 US 147, 15354 (1979). | |
40. | 28 USC § 1738 requires federal courts to give the same preclusive effect to state court judgments as they would be given by another court of that state. See San Remo Hotel, LP v City & County of San Francisco, 545 US 323, 338 (2005). | |
41. | Once there is a final judgment on the merits in an action, res judicata generally precludes a party or their privies from relitigating issues that were or could have been raised in the previous action. Allen v McCurry, 449 US 90, 94 (1980). To determine the preclusive effect of a state court judgment, federal courts look to state law. Palomar Mobilehome Park Assn v City of San Marcos, 989 F3d 362, 364 (9th Cir 1993). | |
42. | California law differs from both federal law and that of a majority of states in that its same cause of action aspect of the res judicata doctrine is based not on a transactional |
70
analysis but upon a primary rights theory. Manufactured Home Communites, Inc v City of San Jose. 420 F3d 1022, 1031 (9th Cir 2005). | ||
43. | Under the primary rights theory, a cause of action consists of (1) a primary right possessed by the plaintiff; (2) a corresponding primary duty on the defendant and (3) a wrongful act done by the defendant constituting a breach of that duty. Agarwal v Johnson. 25 Cal 3d 932, 954-55 (1979). The primary right is the plaintiffs right to be free of the injury suffered. Alpha Mech. Heating & Air Conditioning. Inc. v Traveler Cas & Sur Co of Am. 133 Cal App 4th 1319, 1327 (2005). This right is distinguished from both the theory of liability on which the injury is premised and the remedy sought. If an action involves the same injury to the plaintiff and the same wrong by the defendant then the same primary right is at stake even if in the second suit the plaintiff pleads different theories of recovery, seeks different forms of relief and/or adds new facts supporting recovery. Eichman v Fotomat Corp. 147 Cal App 3d 1170, 1174 (1983). See also Mycogen Corp v Monsanto Co. 28 Cal 4th 888, 897 (2002) (concluding that different theories of recovery are not separate primary rights); | |
44. | The Citys res judicata argument fails because the De Anza litigation does not concern the same primary rights. | |
45. | Here, the relevant primary rights involve the operation of the 1999 Amendments and their application to MHCs property. |
71
While the Ordinances vacancy control provision has not been altered since the De Anza litigation, the operation of the Citys mobilehome rent regulation was altered in 1999 when the automatic rent increase adjustment formula was modified to impose a flat 75 percent of the change in the CPI-C. | ||
46. | The absence of a textual change in the vacancy control provisions themselves does not alter this conclusion. MHC challenges the Citys entire regulatory regime as of 1999. That scheme of regulation may not escape constitutional scrutiny through piecemeal legislation effected by carefully timed amendments as a means of avoiding such scrutiny. | |
47. | This is not a case in which the Ordinances relevant and legal factual components were fixed in 1993 and were not modified after that date. Tahoe-Sierra Preservation Council. Inc v Tahoe Regional Planning Agency. 322 F3d 1064, 1079 (9th Cir 2003). Because the claims presently before the court could not have been asserted in the previous lawsuit, id at 1078, the Citys res judicata argument must fail. |
1. | Injunctive relief is appropriate when an ordinance is deemed unconstitutional under the Takings Clause. Carson Harbor Village. Ltd v City of Carson. 37 F3d 468, 473 n4 (9th Cir 1994); see also Golden Gate Hotel Assn v City and County of San Francisco. 836 F Supp 707, 709 (ND Cal 1993), vacated on |
72
other grounds, 18 F3d 1482 (9th Cir 1994) (permanent injunction against enforcement of an ordinance was justified when the ordinance failed substantially to advance legitimate state interests). | ||
2. | Under Penn Central, if the government has had an opportunity to provide just compensation in response to a taking and fails to do so, the City may be enjoined from continuing to take the property unless or until it provides just compensation. See Penn Central. 438 US at 124. In Eastern Enters v Apfel. 524 US 498 (1998), a four-justice plurality recognized that a federal court may issue an injunction or declaratory judgment concerning whether the governments conduct constituted a taking, even though the plaintiff had not yet sought compensation. See also, for example, Student Loan Marketing Assn v Riley. 104 F3d 397, 402 (DC Cir 1997) (entertaining declaratory relief request despite the availability of compensatory remedy under the Tucker Act; such availability does not wipe out equitable jurisdiction); In re Chateaugay Corp. 53 F3d 478, 491-93 (2nd Cir 1995) (Because the plaintiff sought only declaratory relief on its takings claim, the plaintiff was not required to go to Claims Court first. ). See also Armendariz. 75 F3d at 1321 n5 (Because a private taking cannot be constitutional even if compensated, a plaintiff alleging such a taking would not need to seek compensation in state proceedings before filing a federal takings claim. ). |
73
74
75
76
77
78
/s/ VAUGHN R WALKER | ||||
VAUGHN R WALKER United States District Chief Judge |
79
80
81
82
83
84
85
86
87
88
89
90
91
92
93
94
95
96
97
98